The official version of this document can be found via the PDF button.
The below content has been automatically generated from the original PDF and some formatting may have been lost, therefore it should not be relied upon to extract citations or propose amendments.
STATES OF JERSEY
r
STRATEGIC PLAN 2006 TO 2011 (P.40/2006): ELEVENTH AMENDMENTS
Lodged au Greffe on 5th June 2006 by the Corporate Services Scrutiny Panel
STATES GREFFE
STRATEGIC PLAN 2006 TO 2011 (P.40/2006): ELEVENTH AMENDMENTS ____________
After the word "Appendix" insert the words –
", except that in Commitment One, Outcome 1.2 –
(a) fo r Actions 1.2.2 and 1.2.3 substitute the following Actions –
1 .2 . 2 . Retain any budget surpluses that occur before the introduction of the 0/10 tax changes (due in
2010) in the Consolidated Fund until the extent of any structural deficit as a result of the new fiscal strategy becomes clear with these surplus funds being be used to maintain revenue and capital spending in the short term whilst any structural deficit is addressed (T&R).
1 .2 . 3 .
Improve overall fiscal framework by the immediate establishment of a Stabilisation Fund, into which the
following funds will be transferred –
i. T h e balance of excess funds over liabilities held currently in the Dwelling Houses Loans Fund as they become available (T&R).
ii . T h e capital receipts from property sales identified in Action 6.2.3 ofthis Plan, estimated to
reach at least £4 million per year by 2009 (being the capital element of the savings arising from the Change Programme) (T&R).
ii i. T h e non-capital element of the Change Programme Efficiency Savings identified in 6.2 of
the Strategic Plan (estimated to reach £6.64 million per year by 2009) (T&R).
1 .2 . 4
forward for approval by the States detailed proposals for the control of inflation to update the current inflation
strategy, with the proposals to include details of the future use of the balance in the Stabilisation Fund created under 1.2.3 above and the operation and long term use of the Fund which will be broadly as described in the Economic Growth Plan (P.38/2005) as adopted by the States. The proposals will also cover the role of fiscal measures, particularly GST rates, in this context (T&R) (ED).
CORPORATE SERVICES SCRUTINY PANEL
REPORT
- In troduction
The Panel in considering the draft Strategic Plan at its meeting on 13th April 2006, decided to focus its attention on the Financial Framework as this was linked to its responsibility for scrutinising the States Business Plan and Budget.
- O bjectives
The Panel set out the following objectives for the review –
To examine the original purpose for the establishment of the Dwelling House Loan Fund and to consider the options for the use of the balance in the Loan Fund.
To examine the projected corporate and departmental efficiency savings for the years 2005 to 2009
To clarify the potential extent of the revenue gap (black hole').
To investigate the proposed use of a Stabilisation Fund.
To consider the Minister's enhanced anti-inflation strategy (Strategic Plan 1.2.2)
1.2. S ub-Panel
The Panel decided to invite two additional members, Senators L. Norman and B. Shenton, to join them for th purpose of this review, both being non-Executive members of the States. The Panel subsequently discovered that Scrutiny Panels did not have the power, under Standing Orders, to co-opt other members; however, Sub-Panels did have that ability. The Panel, therefore, decided to form a Sub-Panel to undertake this particular review. The Sub-Panel was constituted as follows –
Deputy P.J. Ryan, Chairman Senator L. Norman
Senator J. Perchard
Senator B. Shenton Constable D. Murphy Deputy J. Gallichan
Officer support: Mr. M. Haden and Miss S. Power
The Panel was of the opinion that a change to Standing Orders should be considered to allow for greater flexibility in respect of co-opting additional members to a Scrutiny Panel in the future.
- I n vestigations
The Panel Chairman and Deputy Gallichan met the Head of Financial Planning, Treasury, and the Director, Property Holdings Department, to discuss the corporate and departmental capital and revenue efficiency savings.
The Panel received a Briefing Note from the Head of Corporate Capital, Treasury, on the Dwelling House Loan Fund, statistical information from the Head of the Statistics Unit and background economic information from the Economic Adviser, Chief Minister's Department.
Relevant papers are available for downloading from the Scrutiny website.
The Panel held a public hearing on 18th May 2006 with the Treasury and Resources Minister who was accompanied by the Treasurer of the States. The transcript is available on the Scrutiny website.
- S u b-PanelFindings
The Sub-Panel considered its findings following the public meeting with the Minister and agreed on the following key points –
the balance of the Dwelling House Loan Fund should not be used to fund initiatives in the Strategic Plan;
the balance of the Dwelling House Loan Fund should be applied instead to the establishment of a Stabilisation Fund
efficiency savings from the Change Programme should be applied to the Stabilisation Fund. This would prove to the public that the States was serious about reducing expenditure.
it would be irresponsible to increase States expenditure above previously agreed levels at this stage when the Island is embarking on a high risk fiscal strategy, the accuracy of the future financial impact of which is still unclear;
the purpose of the Stabilisation Fund should be clarified in the Strategic Plan as at present there was a blurring between: (a) the concept of a Stabilisation Fund, as conceived in the Economic Growth Plan, to address cyclical periods of growth/inflation/recession/deflation in the economy, and (b) the requirement for a fund in which to deposit budget surpluses arising from the introduction of GST to address subsequent structural deficits arising from the introduction of Zero/ten.
an inflation strategy which maintained a strong discipline over public spending should remain a key strategic aim for the Island.
- S ub-Panelrecommendation
The Sub-Panel agreed to recommend to the full Corporate Services Panel that it seek to amend P.40/2006 accordingly.
The full Panel unanimously accepted the recommendation of the Sub-Panel and agreed to adopt, in principle, a draft report prepared by the Chairman, subject to further revision.
2.0 S trategic Plan 2006 to 2011 (P.40/2006): Eleventh Amendments
The Panel's agreed amendments and accompanying report were lodged au Greffe' on 5th June 2006.
After the word "Appendix" insert the words –
", except that in Commitment One, Outcome 1.2 –
(a) fo r Actions 1.2.2 and 1.2.3 substitute the following Actions –
1 .2 . 2 . Retain any budget surpluses that occur before the introduction of the 0/10 tax changes (due in
2010) in the Consolidated Fund until the extent of any structural deficit as a result of the new fiscal strategy becomes clear with these surplus funds being be used to maintain revenue and capital spending in the short term whilst any structural deficit is addressed (T&R).
1 .2 . 3 .
Improve overall fiscal framework by the immediate establishment of a Stabilisation Fund, into which the
following funds will be transferred –
i. T h e balance of excess funds over liabilities held currently in the Dwelling Houses Loans Fund as they become available (T&R).
ii . T h e capital receipts from property sales identified in Action 6.2.3 ofthis Plan, estimated to
reach at least £4 million per year by 2009 (being the capital element of the savings arising from the Change Programme) (T&R).
ii i. T h e non-capital element of the Change Programme Efficiency Savings identified in 6.2 of
the Strategic Plan (estimated to reach £6.64 million per year by 2009) (T&R).
1 .2 . 4
forward for approval by the States detailed proposals for the control of inflation to update the current inflation
strategy, with the proposals to include details of the future use of the balance in the Stabilisation Fund created under 1.2.3 above and the operation and long term use of the Fund which will be broadly as described in the Economic Growth Plan (P.38/2005) as adopted by the States. The proposals will also cover the role of fiscal measures, particularly GST rates, in this context (T&R) (ED).
3.0 R eport on Amendments – Executive Summary
New paragraph 1.2.2 ensures that early GST receipts/budget surpluses do not go into Stabilisation Fund but are held instead to help address structural deficits post 2009.
Forecasts post 2009 suggest structural deficits rising to £40 million in 2013
Re-appraisal of black hole' may reduce but unlikely to eliminate deficits
Stabilisation Fund (SF) intended as counter-cyclical and counter-inflation tool
Clarification of 2008/2009 forecast surpluses not appropriate for SF
New paragraph 1.2.3 accelerates the establishment of a Stabilisation Fund and places funds into it progressively via: (i) the balance of the DHLF, (ii) the capital receipts element of the efficiency savings, and (iii) the remaining un-allocated balance of the revenue efficiency savings.
Numerous refs. to 2005 States decisions limiting public spending growth
Recent success in control of inflation through limits to spending growth
DHLF not income flow'
Places balance of DHLF and efficiency savings into SF
Property capital receipts once spent = slow erosion of property capital base
Achievement or not of Efficiency Savings outside scope of amendment
- Increases deficits byremovalofDwellingHousesLoansFund(DHLF)
- Increases deficits byremovalofcapital element of Efficiency Savings
- Increases deficits by removal of non-capital element of Efficiency Savings (remaining unallocated £6.7 million per annum)
(i), (ii) and (iii) place increasing pressure on the Council of Ministers to reduce/delay spending
New paragraph 1.2.4 provides for the early presentation by Treasury & Resources and Economic Development of a report on the usage, size etc. of the Stabilisation Fund created in new paragraph 1.2.3 for a States debate.
Closes off or converts funds in SF for other uses
No allowance for next recession in forecasts
Report and States decision on usage guidelines, size of fund, fiscal levers etc.
Where are we in the economic cycle
Conclusion
Inflationary pressures
o GST in 2008
o 2% real economic growth annually as per Economic Growth Plan
o end of ITIS deflationary impact in 2007
o proposed RUDL charges to non-Jersey owned businesses
o public spending growth as per Strategic Plan?
Balanced budgets over the full economic cycle rather than the next five years
- A ddressingbudget deficits post2009
- A m endment: New paragraph 1.2.2
This part of the amendment is designed to ensure that budget surpluses created largely as a result of the early introduction of GST in 2008 are held over to address budget deficits evident from 2010 and into the future after the introduction of 0/10 Corporation Tax and the loss of tax receipts from the business sector as a result.
- The Black Hole' in States Resources Forecast
The Resources Forecast (Page 17 of the Strategic Plan) indicates significant budget deficits in 2010 and 2011 as a result of the introduction of the zero/ten fiscal changes, after the surpluses provided in 2008 and 2009 by the introduction of new Goods and Services taxes and revenue raising changes to existing taxes such as 20 means 20'.
The Minister told the Sub-Panel reviewing the Financial Framework that his overall objective was to maintain balanced budgets over the longer term'. However, even over the six year period covered by the Strategic Plan, the forecast is for an overall deficit by the end of the period of £12 million.
The Panel requested the Treasury to provide indicative' figures after 2011 using similar assumptions and growth patterns as used in 2010 and 2011 and any other assumptions such as the phasing out of tax receipts in 2012. The result is shown in Table 1. The size of the continuing deficits forecast for 2012, 2013 and 2014 indicates that there remains a very strong likelihood of a serious structural problem that will need to be addressed from 2010 onwards.
Table 1: Extended Financial Forecast 2012 - 2015
2012 2013 2014 2015 £' m £' m £' m £' m
tes Revenues (2006 Budget) 480 485 500 516 icipated States Revenues – GST, 20/20 56 58 60 61 tential States Revenues 536 543 560 577 enue Expenditure Forecasts 527 540 553 567 ital Expenditure Forecasts 43 44 45 46
tal Net Expenditure Forecasts
enditure growth
nsfer of Parish welfare and residential care (May 06)
tal Net Expenditure Forecasts (inc. Parish transfer)
tribution from Dwelling Houses Loan Fund
ding from Island Rate for transfer of Parish Welfare tal Net Expenditure Forecasts less contributions
enditure growth after DHLF
ft Strategic Plan Surplus/(Deficit)
570 584 598 613
1.0% 2.5% 2.5% 2.5%
10 10 10 10
580 594 608 623 –
10 10 10 10
570 584 598 613
2.3% 2.5% 2.5% 2.5% (33.3) (40.9) (38.5) (35.8)
The Minister advised the Sub-Panel that these figures should be taken with a health warning: they are almost academic; they are sort of a mathematical extension to where we are now, rather than a realistic position.' Referring to the anticipated Black Hole' caused by the fiscal changes he said: Because there are a variety of contributing factors to the £80-£100 million deficit and we are taking a very prudent line, I do not think I will have any nasty shocks in terms of financial forecasts.' When pressed to comment on the possibility that the indicative figures beyond 2011 contained a clear warning of a continual structural deficit, the Minister said: I think it is intended to indicate that we could live within our means within a 5 year period but yet at the end of it, if nothing else changed those figures, there could be difficulties thereafter. I have also said that, inevitably, things will change and those figures will alter. What this is simply indicating is that the strategic policies within this plan over a five year period are capable of being delivered while we still achieve our budget.'
The Sub-Panel noted the encouraging out-turn figures for 2005 as reported in the Financial Report and Accounts and the assurance that the financial forecast would be revised on a regular twice-yearly basis. The Minister told the Sub-Panel: Structural deficits do not happen overnight, and this plan says that over the next 5 years we can achieve balanced budgets. We will review the plan next year. It will not be in December 2010 that we suddenly say: "We have got a problem." We should be aware of that by 2008 and 2009 and plan it accordingly at that time. The whole idea is not to have sudden shocks to the economy but to plan on a rolling programme in advance.'
The Sub-Panel supports the Minister's insistence on the importance of delivering balanced budgets. Despite the assurances of the Minister, however, the Sub-Panel was not convinced that the outlook indicated in the draft Strategic Plan Financial Forecast and beyond provided sufficient confidence for relaxing the tight spending controls of the last few years, as envisaged in the draft Strategic Plan. This is discussed further in the next section.
- T h e Stabilisation Fund
Page 16 of the Strategic Plan (2nd paragraph of Financial Framework) refers to the creation of a stabilisation fund into which will be paid "budget surpluses in times of economic growth" It is not clear as to whether the Council of Ministers intends that the budget surpluses indicated for 2008 and 2009 will be paid into the stabilisation fund, but it is very clear that the surpluses are as a result principally of early GST receipts before 0/10 and not economic growth.
The Strategic Plan does not go into any detail about the proposed Stabilisation Fund; however, it appears to the Panel that what is being proposed is not the same form of Stabilisation Fund as proposed in the Economic Growth Plan (P.38/2005), as agreed by the States., which is designed to address cyclical movements in the economy rather than a structural deficit. For ease of reference the relevant section from the Economic Growth Plan (P38 2005) as approved by the States is included with this report at Appendix A.
The effective control of inflation and the creation of a stabilisation fund are indeed crucial to our future economic well being and future economic competitiveness, but to help with the avoidance of doubt this amendment ensures that budget surpluses as a result of the early GST receipts are retained as a short-term cushion to help to address any residual structural deficits after 0/10 and not confused with the establishment of a true stabilisation fund which is addressed in section six of this report.
- T h e proposed RegulationofUndertakings Licence Fees
The Sub-Panel noted that one of the major proposals contained in the draft Zero/Ten tax changes to take effect in 2010 (currently out for public consultation), involved the charging of licence fees to businesses at a level of £500 per Regulation of Undertakings Manpower Licence (RUDL fees).
It was further noted that although the new locally owned Limited Trading Partnership (LTP) would be able to avoid the RUDL fees through offsetting against personal tax liabilities, non locally owned companies would not be able to follow this avoidance route.
The Minister for Treasury and Resources was questioned about this at a private hearing on the 12th May 2006 by the Sub-Panel dealing with zero/ten' and look through'. The following points became apparent.
- The RUDL fee proposal is deliberately targeted at non Jersey owned companies in order to recover an element of taxation from this sector that would migrate to other jurisdictions under the zero tax regime.
- The size of the fees would be set at zero for the financial services sector so that they would escape increased costs, bearing in mind that they would be taxed at the 10% side of the 0/10.
- The size of the fee for non finance sectors would be driven by the total tax' recovery target of approximately £5m.
- The cost of the fees to non Jersey owned businesses would not be off-settable against any tax in another jurisdiction through a double tax' agreement, (unlike the present 20% Corporation Tax).
- The fees will be irrecoverable by non Jersey owned companies and will represent real increased costs (not offset-able through double taxation agreements with the UK).
- To the extent that these companies enjoy market power' they would be likely to pass on the extra costs to their customers. i.e. the RUDL fees will be inflationary.
- C reation of a StabilisationFund
- A m endment: New paragraph 1.2.3
This amendment addresses the contributions from savings and potential new income flows' in three parts represented by –
- t heDwellingHousesLoansFund(DHLF),
- the £4 million a year savings' from capital receipts; and
- the remainingunallocatednon-capital element of the efficiency savings
This amendment accelerates the establishment of a stabilisation fund, but additionally it has the effect of putting pressure on the Council of Ministers to take action in one of three ways –
- Continue spending plans with increased budget deficits;
- Continue spending plans andincrease taxation to reducebudget deficits; or
- Reducethegrowth in expenditure tothe level foreseenin the 2006Budget report toreduce budget deficits.
For the sake of absolute clarity, the Panel does not advocate actions (1) or (2), but fully expects the Council of Ministers to review their spending plans as a matter of urgency in order to maintain their commitment to delivering balanced budgets and eliminating deficits over the period of the Strategic Plan. Only when it is clear that increased revenues will cover any future deficit should the Council of Ministers embark on its full spending programme.
- I n creased expenditureplansintheStrategic Plan
The Financial Forecast in the 2006 Budget Report, which was agreed by the States in December 2005 (only 6 months ago), shows a series of single figure budget deficits for the period 2006 to 2009 with a very large deficit of £70 million appearing in 2010 with the introduction of the new0/10' corporate tax structure (see Table 2).
To address the immediate forecast deficits the agreed policy of the States in recent years, up to and including the 2006 Budget, has been to constrain public spending within strict limits. The following statements were made in 2006 Budget report -
"These projections also assume that States expenditure increases remain within the modest levels set in the recent States Business Plan debate of an average of around 2.5% per annum over the next 5 years." Page viii Para 1.4
"The Committee's main objectives for the period 2006 to 2010 are to: restrict increases in total States net expenditure to affordable levels, within the expenditure framework in the Fiscal Strategy and States Business Plan" Page x Para 2.4 first bullet point.
"The Committee is not able to control interest rates, however it will continue to endeavour to reduce inflationary pressures by constraining the growth in States spending to a level below the forecasts of inflation." Page xi 2.5 (last para.)
Table 2: Financial Forecast 2006 to 2010 (2006 Budget)
Estimates
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 £' 000 £' 000 £' 000 £' 000 £' 000
Income
Income Tax 385 403 417 432 381 Impôts 46 44 43 41 40 Stamp Duty 17 17 17 17 17 Other Income 24 24 24 24 24
Total Income 472 488 501 514 462
Expenditure and Transfers to Reserves
Total States Net Revenue Expenditure 441 454 467 480 490 Capital Allocation 39 39 39 39 42 Transfer to Strategic Reserve – – – – –
Total States Net Expenditure 480 493 506 519 532 Deficit for the year (8) (5) (5) (5) (70)
"The States approved, in the Business Plan, an increase of 2.7% in total States spending" "The revenue expenditure has increased by 3.8% in 2006" "This increase has only been afforded due to the significant reduction in the capital allocation from £43m in 2005 to £39m in 2006." Page xi 3.1.
"The planning of a five-year programme has been achieved despite a significant reduction in the annual capital allocation from £43m in 2005 and £45m per annum in the years 2006 to 2009 to a new allocation of £39 million per annum for 2006 to 2009, only increasing to £42 million in 2010." Page xv 6.
In contrast to the above statements, the Resources Forecast in the draft Strategic Plan proposes expenditure growth in 2007 and 2008 of 4.3% and 3.8% respectively. The Plan proposes a year on year increase in States revenue and capital expenditure amounting to a total of approximately £57 million in additional spending over a five year period above that envisaged in the 2006 Budget financial forecast. (See Table 3)
The Strategic Plan financial forecast includes a contribution to income of £32 million over the period coming from the balance in the Dwelling House Loan Fund. Cosmetically this appears to reduce the expenditure growth in 2007 and 2008 to 3.5% and 3.2%, yet even this is still in excess of the growth in spending foreseen in the 2006 Budget.
In addition to the balance of the Dwelling House Loan Fund the £20 million of efficiency savings, originally earmarked in the Fiscal Strategy to part fill the Black Hole' deficit caused by zero/ten corporate tax, is now to be reinvested' in new public spending initiatives.
Table 3: Financial Forecast 2006 - 2011 (Strategic Plan Resources Statement)
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m
es Revenues (2006 Budget) 472 488 501 514 462 471 icipated States Revenues - GST, 20/20 – – 47 49 51 53
ential States Revenues 472 488 548 563 513 524 venue Expenditure Forecasts 442 463 479 493 504 518
pital Expenditure Forecasts
al Net Expenditure Forecasts
penditure growth
nsfer of Parish welfare and residential care ay 06)
al Net Expenditure Forecasts (inc. Parish nsfer)
ntribution from Dwelling Houses Loan Fund
ding from Island Rate for transfer of Parish lfare
penditure growth after DHLF and Island Rate ome
jected Surplus/(Deficit)
39 39 42 42 45 46
481 502 521 535 549 564 2.8% 4.4% 3.8% 2.7% 2.7% 2.7%
7 10 10 10 10 10
488 512 531 545 559 574
– 4 7 7 7 7
7 10 10 10 10 10
2.8% 3.5% 3.2% 2.7% 2.7% 2.7%
(9) (10) 34 35 (29) (33)
The difference between the spending plans in the 2006 Budget and the Strategic Plan can be seen clearly by placing the two Total Net Expenditure Forecast lines alongside each other. (See Table 4)
The Minister told the Sub-Panel that the proposed increase in spending was consistent with his policy of a balanced budget: I think we have to balance a variety of requirements that we have. My overall objective is to maintain balanced budgets over the longer term and if by spending some or all of the efficiency savings I was of the view that balanced budgets could not be maintained over the longer term, I would have concerns. I am still of the view that balanced budgets can and must be maintained over the longer term and if we choose to use some of those efficiency savings at the present to maintain our infrastructure, we have to accept the fact that we have at all times to look at the overall policy of those balanced budgets.
Table 4: Comparison of expenditure forecasts
| 2006 Budget | Strategic Plan | Difference |
2006 | 480 | 481 | [1] |
2007 | 493 | 502 | 9 |
2008 | 506 | 521 | 15 |
2009 | 519 | 535 | 16 |
2010 | 532 | 549 | 17 |
2011 |
| 561 |
|
The Council of Ministers claim that the draft Strategic Plan is fully funded from within existing spending limits' but then goes on to qualify this statement "when the contributions from savings and potential new income flows are taken into account".
The Panel believes that this statement should be subject to scrutiny. In the Panel's view, the draft States Strategic Plan represents a significant and premature shift away from the 2006 Budget policy of constrained States expenditure. The key questions are –
Where are the new income flows' and savings coming from? and
What effect might the proposed additional spending have on inflation?
- N ew incomeflows'
- The Dwelling Houses Loans Fund
£32 million of the surplus funds available in the DHLF (from a total balance at the end of 2005 of some £52.7 million) is identified as the key element in the new income flows' which will fund the proposed net increase in States expenditure through to 2011.
A briefing note on this Fund which was provided by the Head of Corporate Capital, Treasury, is attached at Appendix B.
The Panel does not accept that this Fund can be accurately described as a new income flow'. Although it has grown larger over the years as loan capital with extra interest (over that charged to it) has flowed back into the fund from borrowers several times over since the 1950's, once spent there is no further income flow'. There have been very few (if any) new borrowers over the last few years from which continuing income flows through interest charges will derive once the balance of outstanding capital and interest has been returned. The figures for recent years show that the outstanding loans have been run down at a rate of about 15% a year.
A policy in the 1990s that made the interest charges un-competitive against traditional sources of mortgage capital, coupled with a much lower interest rate climate and competition amongst lenders, effectively led to a closing-off of the fund to new borrowers. There is a legitimate argument that the fund should now be returned to its original source if it is no longer required. When the fund was created in the middle of the last century (the fund was created under the Building (Loans) Jersey Law 1950) the Strategic Reserve did not exist, however the argument goes that the fund should now be returned to the nearest fit' source i.e. the Strategic Reserve.
It is probable that had the original funds placed in the DHLF been placed instead in a strategic reserve', had one existed at the time, then over the years similar capital appreciation would have occurred through investment, as has occurred through the DHLF.
The Panel believes that the States' original intention was to retain a strategic public asset whilst at the same time assisting first time buyers of homes on lower incomes. In some ways it might have been better for the Finance and Economics Committee to have been responsible for the administration of the DHLF, with prospective recipients of the loans endorsed by the Housing Committee. The Panel does not believe that the original intention was to convert these funds into future revenue or capital spending at some stage.
The Panel's amendment in sub-paragraph (i) does not follow thereturn to Strategic Reserve' line but it does go some way towards it in that the funds would ebb and flow in the Stabilisation Fund (depending on the cyclical nature of the economy) without theoretically actually being irrevocably spent.
The Panel proposes that, instead of using the Dwelling House Loan Fund to fund additional spending, the balance of excess funds over liabilities should be retained as a strategic asset and transferred to a Stabilisation Fund, as described in section six below.
The effect of the Panel's amendment on the Financial Forecast, as shown in Table 5, is to increase the projected deficits. It should, however, be noted that this is entirely due to the proposed increased spending plans of the Council of Ministers. The inclusion of the Dwelling House Loan Fund in the Strategic Plan masks the impact of the additional spending. Diverting the use of these funds will oblige the Council of Ministers to review their spending increases.
Without increases to spending this table would be roughly equivalent to that presented to the States in the 2006 Budget.
Table 5: Financial Forecast excluding DHLF contribution
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m
evenues (2006 Budget)
ted States Revenues – GST, 20/20 l States Revenues
Expenditure Forecasts Expenditure Forecasts
t Expenditure Forecasts iture growth
of Parish welfare and residential care (May 06) t Expenditure Forecasts (inc. Parish transfer)
tion from Dwelling Houses Loan Fund Contribution from DHLF
472 488 501 514 462 471
– – 47 49 51 53
472 488 548 563 513 524
442 463 479 493 504 518
39 39 42 42 45 46
481 502 521 535 549 564
2.8% 4.4% 3.8% 2.7% 2.7% 2.7%
7 10 10 10 10 10
488 512 531 545 559 574
– 4 7 7 7 7
0 (4) (7) (7) (7) (7)
from Island Rate for transfer of Parish Welfare 7 10 10 10 10 10 Surplus/(Deficit) after Scrutiny adjustments (9) (14) 27 29 (36) (40)
rategic Plan Surplus/(Deficit) (9) (10) 34 35 (29) (33)
- The ChangeProgramme Efficiency Savings
The Change Programme targeted £20 million per annum to be achieved by 2009 mainly through corporate and
departmental efficiencies but also with a capital contribution through the Property Plan.
Appendix C details the latest sources and estimates of the efficiency savings. From its discussions with the Head of Financial Planning and the Director, Property Holding Department, the Panel has seen no reason to suspect that this target is not achievable. The focus of its review has been on how it is proposed to use these savings.
It is clear that the £20 million savings were originally intended to part fill the structural deficit as a result of 0/10 (the black hole'). However, the Minister told the Sub-Panel that the Council of Ministers now believed that we can live within that range, still spend that £20 million, and still achieve balanced budgets over the period. We will do that by making sure by way of prudence on our revenue expenditure and our capital expenditure.'
The efficiency savings are not clearly identified as a separate line in the Resources Forecast table on Page 17. The Panel requested therefore that an amended Forecast be prepared by the Treasury to show the effect of removing these savings from the calculation. Removing the efficiency savings from the Financial Forecast is shown in two parts: (a) the capital receipts and (b) the non-capital element.
- C a pitalreceipts
The Property Plan targets net capital rising from £0.7 million in 2007 to£4 million per annum from 2009 onward. Although there was always an element of the £20 million that would come from capital receipts' in the proposition (P.58/2004) agreed by the States on Public Sector Reorganisation, this was originally to be £5 million and not the latest figure of £4 million, so in fact an extra£1 million is to be saved from revenue expenditure over P.58/2004.
These capital receipts will very slowly erode the capital base of the States property portfolio and if spent will slowly erode the overall level of States Capital Assets. Technically they should not really be described as efficiency' savings, although they do result in an improving cash position for the States through better use and perhaps disposal and/or alternative purchase of property. This can be described as running the property portfolio more efficiently'. However the public perception of efficiency savings' is – efficiency' improvements result in a like for like lower cost of running the public administration and services every year (revenue expenditure) once they have been made.
By placing these capital receipts into the Stabilisation Fund as per amendment sub-paragraph (ii) we maintain the overall capital base of the States. The effect of this amendment on the Financial Forecast is shown in Table 6.
Table 6: Financial Forecast excluding DHLF contribution and capital receipts
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m
Revenues (2006 Budget)
ipated States Revenues – GST, 20/20 tial States Revenues
ue Expenditure Forecasts
Remove Property Capital Receipts
l Expenditure Forecasts
Net Expenditure Forecasts diture growth
er of Parish welfare and residential care (May 06) Net Expenditure Forecasts (inc. Parish transfer)
ibution from Dwelling Houses Loan Fund
Remove Contribution from DHLF
472 488 501 514 462 471
– – 47 49 51 53
472 488 548 563 513 524
442 463 479 493 504 518 1 2 4 4 4
39 39 42 42 45 46
481 503 523 539 553 568
2.8% 4.4% 3.8% 2.7% 2.7% 2.7%
7 10 10 10 10 10
488 513 533 549 563 578
– 4 7 7 7 7
0 (4) (7) (7) (7) (7)
ing from Island Rate for transfer of Parish Welfare 7 10 10 10 10 10 diture growth after Island Rate income 2.8% 4.6% 4.0% 3.0% 2.7% 2.7%
ed Surplus/(Deficit) after Scrutiny adjustments (9) (15) 25 25 (40) (44) Strategic Plan Surplus/(Deficit) (9) (10) 34 35 (29) (33)
- N o n-capitalelementof the efficiency savings
The non-capital element of the efficiency savings amounts to £16 million revenue savings each year by 2009. These savings fall into a different category to the £4 million per year of capital receipts.
The Panel acknowledges that £10 million of the non-capital efficiency savings has already been reallocated by the States in the 2005 and 2006 Budgets. The remaining efficiencies targeted in the section 6.2 of the draft Strategic Plan amount to £6.64 million and are composed of –
£1.3 million through the implementation by 2008 of the Head of Profession model for the finance function within the States (6.2.1);
£1.6 million through transformation of HR and IT functions by 2008 (6.2.2)
£1.5 million revenue savings from property by 2009 (6.2.3)
£0.510 million by centralising customer facing services by 2009 (6.2.5)
£1.9 million through improved procurement arrangements for goods and services by 2009 (6.2.6)
The Panel proposes that, instead of immediately re-investing' these sums into new forms of expenditure from 2007 onwards, the remaining efficiency savings are retained in a stabilisation fund, as explained in section six below. The effect of this amendment on the Financial Forecast is shown in Table 7.
Table 7 Financial Forecast excluding DHLF contribution and capital receipts and non capital revenue savings
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m £' m
Revenues (2006 Budget)
tial States Revenues
ue Expenditure Forecasts
Remove Property Capital Receipts l Expenditure Forecasts
Net Expenditure Forecasts diture growth
er of Parish welfare and residential care (May 06) Net Expenditure Forecasts (inc. Parish transfer)
ibution from Dwelling Houses Loan Fund
Remove Contribution from DHLF
472 488 501 514 462 471
472 488 548 563 513 524
442 463 479 493 504 518 1 2 4 4 4
39 39 42 42 45 46
481 503 523 539 553 568
2.8% 4.4% 3.8% 2.7% 2.7% 2.7%
7 10 10 10 10 10
488 513 533 549 563 578
– 4 7 7 7 7
0 (4) (7) (7) (7) (7)
ing from Island Rate for transfer of Parish Welfare 3 7 10 10 10 10 10 diture growth after Island Rate income 2.8% 4.6% 4.0% 3.0% 2.7% 2.7%
ed Surplus/(Deficit) after Scrutiny adjustments (9) (18) 19 19 (46) (50) Strategic Plan Surplus/(Deficit) (9) (10) 34 35 (29) (33)
- Panel's views
Clearly, if the Panel's amendments regarding the capital receipts and/or revenue efficiency savings are accepted, in addition to the amendment regarding the Dwelling House Loan Fund, the forecast deficits will increase significantly compared to the Forecast shown in the draft Strategic Plan.
The Panel believes that this cumulative revised forecast position reveals starkly the potentially precarious nature of the Island's financial position in 2010 and 2011 as the scale of corporate tax changes take effect.
The Council of Ministers insists in their Strategic Plan that the forecasts for 2010 and beyond must be considered indicative' at this stage and that early action would be taken by the Council of Ministers to address a structural deficit. The Panel accepts that this will be the case and that the Council of Ministers may have legitimate grounds for believing that the future financial position will be much healthier as the full effects of the Fiscal Strategy unfold.
Nevertheless, the Panel does not believe that now is the right time to relax the tight spending controls which have been central to recent States Budgets. The existing spending controls as approved in the 2006 Budget should be maintained until the future position is much clearer with regard to the Black Hole' and any structural deficits remaining after 2011. New paragraph 1.2.3 i) is designed to achieve this position. Additionally, the Panel believes that the significant new information in the Resources Forecast of the Strategic Plan which extends a further year's projections over that presented to the States during the 2006 Budget, and also particularly the information illustrated in the extended forecast to 2015 in Table 1 above, suggests that the States would be well advised to reconsider some of the reinvestment' of the Efficiency Savings agreed by the States in the 2006 Budget, certainly until the eventual position after 2011 becomes clearer. It is for this reason that the Panel has proposed parts (ii) and (iii) of the new paragraph 1.2.3.
As a consequence of the Panel's amendments, it will be necessary for the Council of Ministers to review the extent and the timing of their spending plans. The revenue and capital items identified in the draft Strategic Plan list a series of important new initiatives: the improvement of social housing, home ownership, the income support system, law and order, the need to care for the growing number of elderly people in our population and anti- discrimination measures'
The Panel acknowledges that it may be easy for the Council of Ministers to criticise amendments which will oblige them to rethink their spending plans. They may say that these are the very initiatives which will be threatened by the Panel's amendments.
The Panel does not accept, however, that these social priorities need be abandoned by the Council as it is certain that there are other expenditure projects, for example in the capital programme, which could be re- prioritised.
The Panel does not believe it is within its remit to identify specific changes which will be necessary to the draft Strategic Plan spending initiatives should its amendments be approved. It has not undertaken any such exercise. Indeed, the lack of financial detail in the Plan prevents any detailed analysis. It is for the Council of Ministers to undertake this review and bring forward suitably revised proposals in the States Business Plan.
- In flation Strategy
- A m endment: New paragraph 1.2.4
This amendment makes the policy guidelines of the Stabilisation Fund an urgent priority for the Council of Ministers. The amendment does not attempt to pre-empt due consideration of its purpose, terms of usage, and ideal size, simply to accelerate provision for the initial establishment (in 1.2.3) and thereafter accelerate policy formulation on its use (in 1.2.4). The Panel believes that detailed work on a Stabilisation Fund long before the next recessionary cyclical downturn should be a top strategic aim.
- R e ducing inflation
Appendix D shows Jersey's performance in controlling inflation as compared to the UK (with which we are in currency union) tracked against our levels of increases in public spending over the last decade. Statistics with the large anomaly of increases in local housing costs removed (RPIx) are interesting as well as the normal RPI.
Without the ability to alter interest rates to suit the levels of inflation in our local economy the only (albeit less than perfect) tools we have at our disposal are the control of public spending and fiscal strategy. Both affect the level of money supply in the economy, the former because the States is by far the major single employer and procurer of goods and services, and the latter by reducing or increasing real disposable incomes.
It is true to say that reductions in public spending or increases in taxation take a while to feed through into reducing inflationary pressure. This is especially true for the latter because most of our tax revenue is from direct taxes paid a long time in arrears of the income upon which it is based. N.B. the introduction of GST may change this.
Nevertheless our recent success in controlling inflation (whilst controlling mainly public spending) is in stark contrast to our performance prior to this period. We have only recently begun to reverse the trend of deteriorating economic competitiveness versus our international competitors.
A central tenet of the Economic Growth Plan involves the achievement of 2% real growth. This means 2% above whatever the rate of inflation is in any year; thus, in the current year when the RPI stands at 2.4%, economic growth of 4.4% is required to meet the target. Clearly the higher our inflation rate actually is the more difficult or unsustainable attaining 2% real growth will become.
In the Panel's view, the control of inflation must remain a key strategic aim of this or any Jersey Council of Ministers. The review of the inflation strategy, however, does not receive a mention in the list of top priorities provided on page 14 of the draft Strategic Plan.
- Stabilisation Fund
It would be wrong to anticipate the contents and recommendations of a properly researched report on the merits of a Stabilisation Fund. It is quite possible that the report's findings might not concur with the setting up of such a fund or the practicalities of using such a fund to help promote economic stability. If that were to be the case then it would be up to the Council of Ministers through the Treasury to make recommendations to the States at that point to close off the fund and return the balance in it created with this amendment to general revenues or into the Strategic Reserve or indeed for any other purpose e.g. the creation of a fund to be used for further assistance for low income first time home buyers through shared equity', as they see fit. The point is that the States will have ultimate control on the use of these funds (the DHLF balances and part efficiency savings) through a future debate specifically for this purpose.
The indicative' forecasts for 2010 onwards show structural deficits. A further recommendation from the Treasury regarding how they intend to fill this residual structural deficit after the fiscal changes envisaged in the new Fiscal Strategy' are complete, will be very important. It is possible that some of the balances placed in the Stabilisation Fund with this amendment might need to be transferred into the Consolidated Fund in due course to
help fill the black hole in the medium term.
It should be emphasised that this is not the purpose of the Stabilisation Fund as envisaged in the Economic Growth Plan (P.38/2005), as agreed by the States, and the establishment and use of the Stabilisation Fund, if agreed by the States, to fill structural deficits as opposed to the filling of cyclical deficits should be clearly understood and any longer term temptation to do this resisted.
Our enquiries lead us to believe that there is no provision included for any cyclical recessionary downturn in the figures included in the Strategic Plan Resources Forecast on page 17, and that might add weight to the need to establish the Stabilisation Fund and inform ourselves of its appropriate usage in early course.
No one can predict when and if there will be a next recession in our economy with much accuracy. Suffice to say that statistically it has happened in the UK economy once every 7 to 12 years. Most commentators also agree that monetary control of inflation has had some success in the UK over the last decade in mitigating some of the negatives of economic cycles by smoothing out peaks and troughs.
This should be contrasted with Jersey's past performance in the context of the control of economic cycles. The panel has observed through its research that in times of economic growth and consequent economic confidence, the tendency at the political level has been to spend more, whether through pressure from the public for better infrastructure or services, or a desire to be popular.
This extra spending has undoubtedly in itself driven further economic growth and in turn, population to feed that growth, in some ways producing a self-defeating cycle by driving the demand to provide extra infrastructure and services for the increase in population.
The most difficult political task facing us may be to convince Jersey's population that restricting the money supply in the economy is in the long term interests of the community in times of growth and confidence. This means taking the difficult political decision to adopt a measured deflationary policy that restricts money supply through constrained public spending and fiscal measures during growth and rising inflation, and vice versa in times of recession. In other words the opposite to what Jersey's politicians have done in the past.
To what extent fiscal measures (as well as the control of public spending) can or should be used to adjust money supply in our local economy and therefore act as a lever to control inflationary pressures, is an interesting concept and one that the Panel would expect to be addressed carefully in the report.
7.0 C onclusion
To return to the central question – what will be the effect of the significant increases in spending envisaged in the Strategic Plan as presented?
The Strategic Plan proposals are a clear departure from the successful policies of the last 3 years in containing inflation. They represent a return to previous higher levels of expenditure growth. Higher inflationary pressures fed by this expenditure growth will undermine our ability to attain or sustain the Economic Growth Plan's 2% real growth target.
The Treasury and Resources Minister was confident that the balanced budgets could be maintained over the 5-year period of the Strategic Plan while at the same time increasing public spending. The Panel urges a more cautious approach and makes the following comments –
- The ResourcesForecaston Page 17of the Strategic Plan clearly indicates that balancing the books over the next 5 years will only bepossible if thelargesurplusesas a result oftheearly GST receipts are usedtocover the 2010and 2011 structural deficits. Whathappens after that?
- Balancing the books over a five year cycle' is in any casean extremely suspect policy from an economic theory perspective. More correct would be Balancing the books over the full economic cycle' (inflation/growth through deflation/recession and back again, regardless ofthe time frame). Atwhat position is Jersey currently in the full economic cycle? Amendment 1.2.4 may help our knowledge in this respect.
2008 will see the introduction of a 3% GST. The Treasury accepts that this will lead to price increases of about 3% probably leading to a one-off inflationary hit approaching that level spread over 2008 and 2009 and this is unavoidable.
Any deflationary effect of the introduction of ITIS in 2006 will dissipate through 2007.
The proposed imposition of Regulation of Undertakings licence fees on businesses as part of the 0/10 proposals is likely to be in part inflationary.
The Economic Growth Plan 2% real growth will of itself generate inflationary pressure. The higher our inflation rate is the more difficult or unsustainable attaining 2% real growth will become.
What will be the likely inflation level if we combine these inflationary pressures? Some factors may be unavoidable - but an increase in public spending is not.
Financial and manpower implications
There are no additional manpower costs and no additional financial costs to these amendments. The Panel recognises that the implications of the amendments are to reduce total States net revenue and capital expenditure and that, as a consequence, the Council of Ministers will be required to re-assess its overall programme. This will probably mean a delay in enacting certain initiatives. The Panel is not in a position to identify specific initiatives and believes that this is the responsibility of the Council of Ministers.
APPENDIX A
Extract from Economic Growth Plan (P.38/2005) Chapter 7: Macroeconomic stability
The need for stability
One key requirement for economic growth is the need to provide a stable economy for businesses and consumers to make decisions and this involves getting the macroeconomic policy framework right. A volatile economic cycle of boom and bust imposes costs on the economy which is likely to undermine efficiency and economic growth in the medium and long-term.
While it may be tempting in the short-term to allow the economy to grow rapidly there are real risks to doing so in the long-term, especially if there is limited or no spare capacity in the economy. A sustainable growth policy will focus on consistent growth close to trend (only allowing above trend growth when there is significant spare capacity in the economy) and ensuring that attention is paid to the supply-side of the economy and not just the demand-side.
The danger of not pursuing such a policy is clearly that excessive growth will lead to accelerating inflation and that the only way for the economy to adjust is through a recession. Inflation is therefore bad for economic growth and a sustainable economic growth plan must also include maintaining low and stable inflation.
Many years of experience across different economies have shown that one of the main consequences of high inflation has been greater instability in economic conditions. Periods when demand has been growing more rapidly than output and inflation has risen have been followed by periods when demand and output (and employment) have fallen sharply (the boom and bust cycle). These falls were probably greater than would have been the case had demand and output grown at a steadier and more balanced pace.
In the Jersey sense (and in fact for any economy in a currency union) this implies an important role for fiscal policy in providing stabilisation and controlling inflation. There may be some questions about the efficacy of fiscal policy but when you have no control over interest rates there is little else left in the macroeconomic policy locker.
A critical element could be ensuring that the automatic stabilisers in the economy work as well as possible and where possible actually strengthening them. There could also be a case for increasing the role of discretionary fiscal policy to help smooth out cyclical variations in the economy. Work by the UK Treasury as part of the 5 EMU tests has shown that expenditure taxes can be one of the most effective discretionary tools because of their direct impact on consumption and the fact that in the UK legislation is such that VAT and excise duties can be changed at any point in the year.
In Jersey any consideration of fiscal policy must also take into account policy for the Strategic Reserve. There would be little point in running fiscal surpluses if at the same time there were significant draw downs from the Strategic Reserve or vice versa.
Policy for the Strategic Reserve
It is worth considering first what the purpose of the Strategic Reserve (SR) is. One of the main problems with the debate surrounding the potential use of the SR is that it represents different things to different people. The original intention, however, was it should be used to provide the Island with some level of insulation from external shocks. The SR has not always been used in this way and at different times funded capital projects when the Island was in recession but has also been used to fund tax cuts and/or expenditure increases at times when the economy was growing strongly.
At other times it has been used for investment in economic development.
With the potential for fiscal surpluses now reduced and 0/10 on the horizon it would be a sensible time to clarify the role of the SR. The original amendment to public finance law constitutes that the reserve cannot be used for any purpose other than one specifically recommended by the Finance and Economics Committee and approved by the States. It is therefore possible for F&E to clearly highlight the circumstances under which they are likely to come forward with such a recommendation.
The international experience
Both Guernsey and the Isle of Man have Strategic Reserves. The Isle of Man has been making substantial contributions to its Strategic Reserve in recent years. It currently has a stated policy of planning for annual budget surpluses of at least 5% of net spending, though there appear to be no explicit policies on the use of the Strategic Reserve.
Guernsey has a Contingency Reserve Fund of £176 million, the purpose of which"is to provide protection against major emergencies including economic downturns having a severe adverse effect on the Island".
Apart from our competitor off-shore finance centres the other countries identified as possessing Strategic Reserves are mainly those which benefit from significant oil revenues. Norway is often cited as the best example of a country which has used its windfall oil revenues wisely. It created the Government Petroleum Fund (GPF) in 1990 into which oil revenues are transferred. The stated purpose of the GPF is to "serve as a tool for coping with the financial challenges from the ageing population and the expected decline in oil revenues by transferring wealth to future generations".
During the 1990s US States created budget stabilization (rainy day) funds to help provide countercyclical support. Today 46 states have such rainy day funds although many have failed to adopt either contribution or expenditure rules that would create significant balances in the funds. Such funds have some general properties:
• They are designed to accumulate revenues during periods of strong economic performance
• They can improve a state's credit rating by demonstrating that a State has significant reserves to weather a moderate recession
• They are designed to be counter cyclical but not to address a structural budget deficit.
• They sometimes have contribution rules
• Withdrawals are often part of the political process and only sometimes based on specific rules.
• Suitable levels for such rainy day funds to be able to provide counter cyclical aid is estimated by some analysts to be in the region of 15-20% of state spending.
What is the Strategic Reserve?
In order to make sensible decisions about the use of the Strategic Reserve it is important to understand exactly what – economically – it is.
Fundamentally the Strategic Reserve represents consumption foregone in previous years by the residents of the Island. Adding to the Strategic Reserve reduces current consumption in the Island and increases the potential for consumption in the future. Spending the Strategic Reserve increases current consumption, but removes the potential for increased consumption in the future.
It is similar to the opposite of borrowing – which has the effect of increasing current consumption but requires future taxpayers to pay interest on the loan, and to repay the capital, thus reducing future consumption. However, the Strategic Reserve differs from borrowing in the following ways:
• It reverses the intergenerational payment pattern. Those who have "paid" for it may well be not around to benefit from the future benefits (because they have left the Island).
• Strategic Reserve financing is cheaper than borrowing – by the difference between interest paid on debt and interest/return earned on assets
The Strategic Reserve and borrowing also have a number of similar traits
• Spending the SR and borrowing will both increase inflationary pressure in the economy
• Both can be used to finance counter-cyclical spending
• Both can be used to smooth the impact of external shocks
• Both can be used to finance direct current consumption, or real economic investments
• Both can lead to a larger public sector than would otherwise have been the case and crowd out' activity in the private sector.
Problems to avoid
The above analysis of what the SR is, past experience with the reserve and the experience of other countries spells out lessons for its future operation. There are a number of pitfalls to avoid:
• Using the reserve to boost spending at times when the economy is close to/above full capacity
• Continual calls for the use of the reserve which waste time and distract attention from the real issues
• Using the reserve but never making repayments
• Funding inappropriate government intervention
• Inadequate provision for future generations that could face a different life in Jersey.
A new framework
Drawing this analysis together suggests that the two most important objectives are to:
- Maintain the Strategic Reserve at close to current levels to maximise the potentialcushion/benefit for future generations in timesof severe structural decline/natural disasters. This implies that a greater value is placedon maintaining future consumption (under specific circumstances) rather than consumption today ortomorrow in general terms.
- Provide some flexibility to tackle short-termcyclicalpressures brought aboutby a cyclical downturn in the economy(fromexternalor internal factors).
The first point actually requires the SR to be put tightly under lock and key so that it is untouchable by the current generation (unless the Island is hit by a major shock). The second point actually requires some flexibility and resources to be available at times of cyclical downturn. Is it possible to reconcile these conflicting objectives?
The only pragmatic way to reconcile these conflicting objectives would be to have two separate funds, with strict rules governing both, say the Strategic Reserve and a new Stabilisation Fund (SF). The real question is how would they operate?
Strategic Reserve
The SR would be maintained at or above current levels (say 90% of government expenditure) in much the same way, with fiscal surpluses invested in the fund or used to replenish the Stabilisation Fund (discussed below). Similarly, the real return from the reserve would be added to the reserve, although it could at times be used to replenish the Stabilisation Fund.
The Strategic Reserve would solely be for the purpose of protecting the standard of living of future generations in the Island when the economy faces severe structural decline or a natural disaster. It would be off limits for all other purposes and this could be made clear from the outset. The circumstances in which the SR could be accessed would be set out clearly in advance.
The only other call on the Strategic Reserve would be an initial payment to capitalise the SF. Stabilisation Fund
The new SF would be governed by strict but transparent rules that only allow it to be used at times of a cyclical downturn. There would be a set trigger mechanism before which the SF would be off limits. The trigger mechanism could be one or more of the following examples:
• Government revenue/expenditure falls by 10 or 20% below expected trends.
• Unemployment rises above an agreed level.
• GVA declines significantly in any calendar year (or if data allowed in two consecutive quarters).
• Profitability of the financial services industry falls by more than 10% in any one year.
There could be pitfalls with any of the above measures e.g. the first one could lead to incentives to be over optimistic with revenue/expenditure trends, issues of data timeliness and frequency, so it might well be the case that the trigger mechanism would be need to be based on at least two different indicators. It is also apparent that such trends would have to be precipitated by cyclical factors and this might be difficult to assess. However, it might also be justified to allow significant structural factors to be addressed for the first year with the SF while full consideration is given to the right policy response to address the structural change.
A decision would have to be made as to whether a trigger mechanism would be needed to make payments to the SF (or SR) at times when the economy was growing quickly. If there was a requirement to do so and it meant that the fiscal stance had to be tightened there would be a countercyclical effect. The alternative would be to leave such payments to the discretion of F&E/The Jersey Chancellor at the risk they would not be made a sufficient rate to be truly countercyclical.
The SF could have a target level e.g. 15% of government expenditure. When it falls below the target rate it would be expected that in times of cyclical upturn payments would be made into the SF – through fiscal surpluses (and/or possibly the real return on the SR) and these could be based on fixed rules.
The experience from the US is that States will not draw on such funds if the rules are too mechanical i.e. they will not draw down funds in year 1 if there is an immediate requirement to repay them in year 2. It could be the cas that firmer rules are required in Jersey similar to those set out for drawing down the SF or that exact decisions about repayments are made by the Jersey Chancellor.
The initial capitalisation of the SF would be an issue. However, this could be done by an initial (one off) payment from the SR and by absorbing other funds. The SF could be built up further if needed over several years if the real return on the SR/fiscal surpluses allowed. The aim could be to have it operational by 2006 for the first Jersey Chancellor. Currently projections for the SR suggest that it could amount to £445 million or 94% of government revenue in 2006 based on a 3.89% annual return. This would allow an initial and one-off payment of £20m into the SF and still keep the SR at 90% of government revenue. Additional payments could be made from any real return in these years.
Such a framework would be drawing on the international experience from such funds and tailoring it to meet the specific requirements and circumstances of Jersey. It would draw on the experience with oil funds in countries like Norway and the Rainy Day Funds' used by US States. The UK Treasury has identified the need for a more flexible fiscal regime if the UK entered EMU and while they are not in favour of a stabilisation fund as such they do recognise the need to strengthen automatic stabilisers and discretionary fiscal policy. Their fiscal rules are already based over the economic cycle and therefore allow the flexibility that this approach would give to Jersey.
Clearly for a Jersey Chancellor to make the right decisions at times of cyclical slow down and with a SF at their disposal further research would be needed in Jersey on the role played by automatic stabilisers and how best to use discretionary fiscal policy. In particular how funds released from the SF could best be used to mitigate a cyclical downturn e.g. tax cuts (direct or indirect) versus maintaining expenditure (capital or current).
Chapter summary and actions
A critical part of the Economic Growth Plan is to provide a new macroeconomic framework for Jersey that represents a clear break with the past. If sustainable economic growth is to be achieved with low inflation then the States of Jersey must ensure that fiscal policy - the one macroeconomic tool available - is focused on delivering the stability required. A transparent and credible framework is required to support stability and control inflation. The Economic Development Committee offers its full support to the Finance and Economics Committee in working towards a new framework for the Strategic Reserve and Fiscal Policy that encapsulates the proposals in this report for a new counter cyclical Stabilisation Fund, with the Strategic Reserve clearly put to one side to be used only if the Island faces a major shock to its economy. |
APPENDIX B
Briefing Note: Dwelling House Loan Fund States of Jersey Treasury
To: Julian Morris From: Ray Foster Cc: Date: 2/5/06
Financial Framework - Draft Strategic Plan: Dwelling Houses Loans Fund
Further to the Panel's request, the following background information is provided:
- The Dwelling Houses Loans Fund(DHLF)is administered under the Buildings (Loans) Jersey Law 1950 (last revised 31/8/2004).
- The DHLFwasestablished in orderto lend moneyto individuals (as identified in therelevantLaw)to acquire a house.Inthe initial years the Fund received cash injections totalling £3.753 million from States general revenues. Over the years the rate of interest charged onloans to borrowershasexceeded the rate of interest charged to the Fund and a surplus has accrued.
- The intention of the States Loanscheme is to provide financial subsidy to thosewho need support in acquiring a property and repaying a mortgage,thosewho are able topaymoredoso.Onceanindividual's incomeis sufficient to pay a commercialrateunder the current rules they doso.
T h e c urrent commercial rate is higher than a borrower would normally pay in the private sector, which is
an incentive to individuals to leave the States scheme when they are able.
- At 31/12/2005, the DHLF had an accumulated fund balance of some £52.7 million – of this, £13.5 million relates to loansand interest outstanding.
T h e r emaining £39.2 million represents a temporary advance from the DHLF to the (then) Capital Fund
Under the Public Finances (Jersey) Law 2005, the Capital Fund has been superseded by the Consolidated Fund.
A copy of the accounts is attached.
- The surplus currently accruingon the Fund hasno particular purpose under the administering law. The terms of Article 2 of the Building Loans (Jersey) Law1950states"there shall be established a fund, to be called the "Dwelling-Houses Loan Fund" (in this Law referred to as "the Fund"), into which the States may pay, and from which the States may withdraw, such sums as they shall from time to time determine."
- It is proposed that £12 million of the current surplus be allocated to increase the funding available to the 2007 – 2011 Capital Programme – principally to provide for refurbishment and redevelopmentofStates social housing. This proposal will beconsidered by theCouncilof Ministers on11May 2006 and, if adopted, will be included intheStatesAnnual Business Plan to bediscussed in September 2006.
- When considering howthe accumulated surplus should be appropriated, the States will need to consider a numberof factors including:
• the need to agree a Strategic Reserve policy (Strategic Plan aim 9.1.7);
• the impact on the economy of a potential significant one off' increase in government expenditure (inflation and impact on construction sector capacity);
• the need to ensure that a funding requirement is not created that will remain once the surplus has been exhausted;
• the impact on the States general revenues cash flow.
Ray Foster
Head of Corporate Capital
Dwelling House Loan Fund
Income and Expenditure account for the year ended 2005
2005 2004
£ £ £ £
ME
terest charged to
rrowers 1,394,829 1,630,954 terest from advances
Capital Fund 1,634,493 1,346,953
ening Balance
terest Adjustment 0 0 3,029,322 2,977,907
NDITURE
ministrative expenses 117,892 122,486 d debt 0 0
(117,892) (122,486) lus/(deficit) for the year 2,911,429.32 2,855,422
Balance Sheet as at 31st December 2005
2005 2004
£ £ £ £
DS EMPLOYED
cumulated Fund
lance at start of year 49,804,500 46,949,078 rplus/(loss) for the
ar 2,911,429 2,855,422
52,715,929 49,804,500 52,715,929 49,804,500
ESENTED BY:
ans and interest
tstanding 13,457,869 15,611,931
rrent assets
btors 5,911 0 btor – Temporary
vance to Capital Fund 39,276,522 34,192,569
39,282,434 34,192,569
rrent Liabilities
editors 24,373 0
(24,373) 0 52,715,929 49,804,500
Projected Profile of Corporate and Departmental Efficiency Savings
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Total £'000 £'000 £'000 £'000 £'000 £'000
orate Efficiencies
300 400 700 500 440 940
ce 206 494 427 1,127 ement 150 300 750 700 1,900 Support Services 1,156 1,634 1,177 700 0 4,667
Departmental 120 120 120 120 480
tive Overheads 330 330 660
ty
enue 400 500 600 1,500
ital 700 1,600 1,700 4,000 Corporate Efficiencies 1,276 2,154 2,827 3,350 1,700 11,307 57% tmental Efficiencies 4,724 1,846 1,173 650 300 8,693 43% t 6,000 4,000 4,000 4,000 2,000 2,000
This new Allocation schedule was presented to the Finance and Economics Committee and CMB in December 2005 by the Change Team.
States Net Revenue Expenditure and Capital Expenditure 1990 to 2005 compared against inflation re 1 Jersey Inflation 1990 to 2005
ey Retail Price s Index, Annual Averages June 2000 = 100
Jersey (June 2000 = 100)
items RPI % change RPI (X) % change
- 65.7
- 71.0 8.1
- 75.3 6.1
- 78.2 3.9
- 80.3 2.7
- 83.2 3.6
- 85.8 3.1
- 89.0 3.7
- 92.9 4.4
- 96.2 3.6 1999 96.6
- 100.4 4.4 2000 100.4 3.9
- 104.2 3.8 2001 104.3 3.9
- 108.7 4.3 2002 108.8 4.3
- 113.4 4.3 2003 113.7 4.5
- 118.9 4.9 2004 117.5 3.3
- 122.6 3.1 2005 120.3 2.4
ce: Jersey Statistics Unit
re 2 UK Inflation 1990 to 2005
United Kingdom CPI
United Kingdom (January 1987 = 100) (2005=100 = 100)
items RPI % change RPI (X) % change % change
- 126.1 1990 122.1 1990 71.5
- 133.5 5.9 1991 130.3 6.7 1991 76.8 7.4
- 138.5 3.7 1992 136.4 4.7 1992 80.1 4.3
- 140.7 1.6 1993 140.5 3.0 1993 82.1 2.5
- 144.1 2.4 1994 143.8 2.3 1994 83.8 2.1
- 149.1 3.5 1995 147.9 2.9 1995 86 2.6
- 152.7 2.4 1996 152.3 3.0 1996 88.1 2.4
- 157.5 3.1 1997 156.5 2.8 1997 89.7 1.8
- 162.9 3.4 1998 160.6 2.6 1998 91.1 1.6
- 165.4 1.5 1999 164.3 2.3 1999 92.3 1.3
- 170.3 3.0 2000 167.7 2.1 2000 93.1 0.9
- 173.3 1.8 2001 171.3 2.1 2001 94.2 1.2
- 176.2 1.7 2002 175.1 2.2 2002 95.4 1.3
- 181.3 2.9 2003 180.0 2.8 2003 96.7 1.4
- 186.7 3.0 2004 184.0 2.2 2004 98 1.3
- 192.0 2.8 2005 188.2 2.3 2005 100 2.0
ce: Office for National Statistics Source: Office for National Statistics
Figure 3 – States Net Revenue Expenditure and Capital Expenditure 1990 to 2005
Revenue | Capital | Combined Revenue + Capital | |
-Trading Committees Net Revenue Expenditure | Expenditure from Capital Fund |
| Total Expenditure |
Annual Index Increase (1990 = £m 158 181 199 209 219 227 237 255 278 294 324 356 377 397 417 423 % 100)
9.9 125.9 5.0 132.3 4.8 138.6 3.7 143.7 4.4 150.0 7.6 161.4 9.0 175.9
10.2 205.1 9.9 225.3
5.3 251.3 5.0 263.9 1.4 267.7 | £m 61 63 51 49 75 68 72 70 67 61 31 42 44 50 42 47 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 | 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 | Annual Index Increase (1990 = £m 219 244 250 258 294 295 309 325 345 355 355 398 421 447 459 470 % 100) 23.8 100.0 11.4 111.4 2.6 114.4
0.4 134.8 4.8 141.4 5.0 148.5 6.3 157.8 2.8 162.1 0.1 162.3 12.1 182.0 192.6 204.4 209.7 214.7 5.8 6.1 2.6 2.4 |
|
|
|
|
[1]
The difference in this case between £480m and £481m is accounted for by the States decision to increase expenditure by £300k to fund television licences for the elderly. This tipped the rounding to £442k and £455k.